Unions, Bargaining Power, and Income Inequality
Yesterday the Bureau of Labor Statistics released their
annual data on labor force unionization. It did not catch any headlines because
it was not surprising. Union membership rates continued to decline in 2014 to
11.1% of the workforce. To many Americans, unions seem like relics. The labor
union has become a fringe institution. But for the last few years, I have
thought a lot about the connection between the decline of labor unions and the
rise of income inequality in the United States. Income inequality has become a
hot button issue this decade, but few are making the explicit connection
between the declining bargaining power of labor and the widening gap between
rich and poor.
On November 4th 2014 Eduard
Porto had a piece in the NY Times on how best to mitigate the growing
income inequality in the United States. Porto’s thesis is essentially that
direct redistribution of wealth has not effectively created a more egalitarian
society and different, alternative methods need to be placed on the table. I
take some issues with Porto’s analysis of redistribution efforts. Many argue
that American wealth redistribution is ineffective and our system allows for
even more corporate rent seeking that distorts any positive redistribution
effects. Nevertheless, his suggestion is valid in that redistribution alone
does not necessarily address the root causes of growing income inequality.
Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century can
take a lot of credit for reintroducing the subject of redistribution into the
American discourse. His use of a broad historical approach to analyze the
structural realities of wealth inequality has garnered a lot of well-deserved
attention. He argues that as we move back to a low-growth regime, which has
been the historical norm, the rate of return on capital relative to growth will
increase (r>g) and with it the importance of inherited wealth and structural
inequality. This has led to more people advocating for direct redistribution
from the wealthiest to the rest in order to establish a more egalitarian
society.
While this analysis deserves attention and further
discussion, the value of Porto’s point is valid in that inequality is a
multidimensional issue and there are several causes to consider. Redistribution
only addresses part of the problem. One vital cause that is present in the
literature, but absent in the public discourse, is the institutional change
that has occurred in the labor-management landscape since the 1980s. Proto
mentions at the end of his piece,
“To
the extent that widening inequality is caused by the yawning gap between the
epicurean pay deals in the executive suite and the stagnant wages paid to those
on the shop floor, it might best be addressed at the level of the corporation,
not by government.”
What Porto is suggesting here is that the bargaining power
of labor has significantly weakened relative to that of the managers and
top-earners in the labor market. How has the bargaining power changed over the
last half-century and how has this contributed to income inequality? What kind
of institutional changes could reverse the trend of growing income inequality?
First let us look at how inequality has changed over the
last 50 years or so.
Figure 1 shows the GINI coefficient of the United States
from the end of World War II to 2012. The GINI is not the most telling measurement
of inequality, but it is widely used and understood. For our purposes, it
reveals the undeniable reality of growing inequality. The First and Second
World Wars, and their aftermath, saw a compression of income inequality. By the
1970s, inequality begins to rise significantly and by the 1980s the trend picks
up speed.
There is a wide literature on causes of income inequality. Scholars like Thomas Lemieux (2013)
make the argument that wage setting institutions like labor unions play a vital
role in establishing levels of inequality. He provides empirical evidence that
the de-unionization of the American workforce contributed to rising inequality,
particularly at the extreme ends of the earnings spectrum. He also suggests
that this might explain why the United States and the United Kingdom, which
have declining unionization rates, have experienced rising inequality while
other advanced economies have not.
Likewise, Calderon and
Chong found statistical evidence that de-unionization, along with other
labor market institutions, significantly influences income inequality. Not only
is there evidence of de-unionization increasing income inequality overall, but Richard Child Hill found
evidence that unionization created a more egalitarian distribution of income
between black and white workers in the United States.
In figure 2, we can see the U.S. unionization rate since the
end of World War II. The trend is unmistakable. Unionized labor has been
declining since its height in the mid-1950s. Particularly since the 1980s,
unions have fallen out of fashion in the American labor market and American
public opinion.
However, organized labor only represents half of the story.
On the other side of the earnings spectrum we have seen a dramatic change as
well. The wealthiest Americans have seen their income increase significantly
during the same period of time. The graphic below shows the share of national
income going to the wealthiest 10% of Americans, from 1948 to 2013.
Once again, the trend is clear. Since the late 1970s and
early 1980s, the wealthiest 10% of Americans have seen their share of national
income increase dramatically. I use the top 10% because within that decile are
primarily individuals who earn their income as managers, lawyers, and through
various sources of white-collar labor. At the 1% level, and more so at the 0.1%
level, we would see a similar trend. However, within that group capital
earnings become more significant, which is a topic for another discussion.
Piketty notes that this radical change in compensation for
the very wealthy followed a cultural and ideological shift in America. With a
return to a more classical economic perspective, many Americans saw
compensation as a purely market function. As such, wages should reflect the
marginal productivity of workers. The higher compensation, therefore, reflects
their marginal productivity and market value of the super-managers.
Marginal productivity, as a mechanism for setting compensation levels, has been challenged by many political economists (i.e. Marx's labor value theory). Most recently, Piketty argues that it is extremely difficult to make the case that the compensation of high income earners reflects marginal productivity since they do not have a clear reproducible
task that can be easily measured the way additional units of output on a factory floor can be. Besides, it is absurd to
suggest that the marginal productivity of a senior manager has changed so
significantly over such a short period of time.
Piketty argues that the
increase follows the change in compensation practices that allow top executives
to set their own salaries or otherwise have salaries set by corporate
compensation committees, which are made up of members who earn similar
salaries. This trend followed changes in social norms within the United States
and the UK (but not the rest of the Western world) that viewed such extravagant
compensation as legitimate. So even compensation set by stockholders is likely
a reflection of arbitrary enthusiasm for profits (meanwhile real wages have
been stagnant for poor and middle class workers). This significantly boosts the
relative bargaining power of top managers.
So where can we go from here?How do we boost earnings at the lower-end of the spectrum and dampen the earnings at the top to a more sustainable and equitable level?
The
Dode-Frank bill passed in 2010 has at least started the public discussion
on regulating executive pay. The rules hashed out by the SEC and other
regulators include non-binding shareholder votes on executive compensation or
so called “say-to-pay votes”, requires disclosure of compensation versus
performance evaluations, and assets the independence of compensation
committees, among other things. However, this is likely to have little affect
on bridging the gap in bargaining power between the wealthy and the poor. There
needs to be a bottom-up approach to reorganizing labor and empowering them to
justly bargain for compensation that more accurately reflects what they add in
value to a product or service.
Many labor advocates long for the days when labor unions
were at their peak. However, unions have had their fair share of problems:
cronyism, racism, and political rent-seeking to name a few. Americans tend to
have a poor opinion of labor unions, which makes them a hard sell to the
public. Additionally, the labor landscape has changed significantly. Workers
move between fields, careers, and positions with more fluidity than in the
past.
While traditional unions might still have a role, other
organizing units might become more important. The alt-labor movement has picked
up speed since the 1990s. alt-labor organizations are not unions, in that they
do not have collective bargaining rights, but they allow for workers to
organize, protest, and form a collective voice. This has allowed for quick mass
mobilization. Groups like the Coalition of Immokalee Workers and the Restaurant
Opportunities Center have been effective for uniting dissenters from within
their working communities. Such organizations could find fertile ground among
the Walmart greeters and Starbucks baristas.
Another alternative could be for workers to take on a more
entrepreneurial approach. I do not mean that workers should all take out loans
and start a business of their own.
Duflo and Banerjee revealed in their book Poor Economics that the majority of the world’s poor are in fact
entrepreneurs. In other words, most men and women living on a dollar a day are
running micro-enterprises of their own. Most of these businesses are
operationally low-hanging fruit. The last thing we want is to reproduce this
model in the United States.
The economist Richard Wolff has a different idea. In his
book Democracy In Action: a Cure for
Capitalism, Dr. Wolff describes the idea of
Workers-Self-Directed-Enterprises (WSDE). The WSDE is a practical application
of Marx’s labor value theory. The WSDE is a company that is owned and operated
by the workers. The workers themselves are the shareholders and board members
of the company. While this is difficult to implement on a large scale,
implementing more worker entrepreneurial enterprises will raise the wages of
labor while mitigating the astonishing rise of management’s compensation.
Ultimately, we might want to see an expansion of a variety of different approaches. This will include labor unions, alternative labor
movements, and new creative ways to blur the line between labor and management, giving workers more autonomy and freedom to bargain for a bigger slice of the profits.
This might begin the process of making the bargaining landscape more
egalitarian and reducing inequality in the United States. The one thing that is clear is that if we ignore the bargaining dynamic at play, and its contribution to growing inequality, we can drift towards an ever-widening gap between the wealthy and the rest, which will have disastrous consequences for our society.
Comments
Post a Comment